Trade and poverty- Is there a connection

Openness and trade liberalization are now seen almost universally as key components of the national policy cocktail required for economic growth and aggregate economic well-being. They are believed to have been central to the remarkable growth of industrial countries since the mid-20th century and to the examples of successful economic development since around 1970. The continued existence of widespread and abject poverty, on the other hand, represents perhaps the greatest failure of the contemporary global economy and the greatest challenge it faces as we enter the 21st century. This essay asks whether the two phenomena are connected. Specifically it asks whether the process of trade liberalization or the maintenance of a liberal trade regime could have caused the poverty that so disfigures modern life, or whether, in fact, it has contributed to its alleviation.

pdf26 trang | Chia sẻ: haohao89 | Lượt xem: 1746 | Lượt tải: 0download
Bạn đang xem trước 20 trang tài liệu Trade and poverty- Is there a connection, để xem tài liệu hoàn chỉnh bạn click vào nút DOWNLOAD ở trên
43 A. Introduction The issue Openness and trade liberalization are now seen almost universally as key components of the national policy cocktail required for economic growth and aggregate economic well-being. They are believed to have been central to the remarkable growth of industrial countries since the mid-20th century and to the examples of successful economic development since around 1970. The continued existence of widespread and abject poverty, on the other hand, represents perhaps the greatest failure of the contemporary global economy and the greatest challenge it faces as we enter the 21st century. This essay asks whether the two phenomena are connected. Specifically it asks whether the process of trade liberalization or the maintenance of a liberal trade regime could have caused the poverty that so disfigures modern life, or whether, in fact, it has contributed to its alleviation. Extreme poverty—living on, say, $1 a day per head— is basically restricted to the developing countries, and so I focus exclusively on them. I also focus largely on the effects of those countries’ own trade policies—i.e. how their own openness or trade liberalization might affect their own poverty. In almost all circumstances countries are more affected by their own trade policies than by their partners’, and, of course, it is the former over which they have most influence. As will become plain, however, most issues concerning partners’ policies or shifts in world markets can be analyzed using the same tools as I discuss below for countries’ own policies. The approach If trade liberalization and poverty were both easily measured, and if there were many historical instances in which liberalization could be identified as the main economic shock, it would be simple to derive simple empirical regularities linking the two. Unfortunately, none of these conditions is met, and so we are reduced to examining fragmentary evidence on small parts of the argument.2 The key to interpreting this evidence in terms of the effects of trade on poverty, as well as to designing policies to alleviate any ill effects, is to understand the channels through which such effects might operate. That is, in the absence of clear empirical regularities, we need to develop a theory of how trade shocks might translate into poverty impacts in order to consider how plausible such links look in the light of what we do know about the way economies function; to identify the places in which it would be sensible to seek empirical evidence; and to help us to fit the jigsaw puzzle of fragmentary evidence into a single overall picture. It will be obvious from the previous paragraph that tracing the links between trade and poverty is going to be a detailed and frustrating task, for much of what one wishes to know is just unknown. It will also become obvious below that most of the links are very case- specific. Hence general answers of the sort “liberalization of type a will have poverty impacts of type b” are just not available—poverty impacts will depend crucially on specifics such as why people are poor to start with, whether the country is well-endowed with mineral wealth and what sort of infrastructure exists. Rather the essay will develop a way of thinking about the poverty effects of trade and trade reform, ending up with a series of questions which will help policy makers to predict the effects of specific reforms. In the broadest possible terms, the essay concludes that trade liberalization is generally a strongly positive contributor to poverty alleviation—it allows people to exploit their productive potential, assists economic growth, curtails arbitrary policy interventions and helps to insulate against shocks. The essay recognizes, however, that most reforms will create some losers (some even in the long run) and that some reforms could exacerbate poverty temporarily. It argues, however, that in these circumstances policy should seek to alleviate the hardships caused rather than abandon reform altogether. A yardstick for economic policy The fact that trade reforms can create some losers means that one needs to be explicit about the criteria for judging policy shocks. If one’s approach is to condemn any shock that causes even one individual to suffer a reduction in income, it is unnecessary to carry out any analysis. Given the differences of interest between people and the strongly redistributive nature of trade policy internally, virtually any policy will fail this test. Even the requirement that no household fall temporarily into poverty is likely to be extremely restrictive in poor countries. The more utilitarian view that the number of households (or persons) in poverty should not increase may be more appropriate although even then consideration of the depth of poverty is also required. Trade and Poverty: Is There a Connection? L Alan Winters1 1 This essay was prepared at the request of the World Trade Organization. It is largely based on research reported in two papers presented as background studies to the World Bank's World Development Report 2000/1 Winters (2000a,b). I am grateful to the UK Department for International Development for financial support and encouragement of the original work, to Xavier Cirera for research assistance, Shoshana Ormonde for logistical help and to Tricia Feeney, Kate Jordan, Caroline Lequesne, Michael Lipton, Neil McCulloch, Andrew McKay, Pradeep Mehta, Chris Stevens, Sally-Ann Way, Howard White, and participants in the World Bank's meeting on 'Openness, Macroeconomic Crises and Poverty' Kuala Lampur, May 10-12th 1999 for comments and advice. The papers draw on field research conducted by Oxfam and the Institute of Development Studies in Africa (Oxfam—IDS, 1999) and Consumer Unity Trust Society in India (CUTS, 1999). I am grateful to their authors for making it available. 2 For example, the fact that trade liberalization in South-East Asia was associated with great strides in alleviating poverty is not sufficient to show that it caused those strides; too much else was going on. Similarly, the (mixed) evidence that liberalization has gone with increasing poverty in Latin America since 1980 is not sufficient to prove the opposite. I do not seek to define to the appropriate metric for judging policies here, but it is important to be aware in considering the arguments below that all judgements ultimately have to be quantitative, not just qualitative. What is poverty? An important aspect of any analysis of poverty is the definition and measurement of the phenomenon itself. While recognizing that there are many legitimate approaches to this, I implicitly adopt here an absolute consumption—or, where necessary, absolute income— metric.3 In choosing this definition, I am not denying the importance of other aspects based, for example, on human development or social exclusion. I believe, however, that the first step towards understanding the effects of international trade on poverty is to focus on the simplest, most directly-impacted and easily-observable dimension of the question. Besides, the different dimensions of poverty are at least fairly well correlated, so that conclusions about income-poverty will be a reasonable indicator of other aspects. A second measurement issue is how to combine the individual poor into an index of poverty. The standard approach among poverty-scholars is to define a poverty line and then measure one of three statistics—see, for example, Ferriera and Litchfield (1999). The first is the number of households (or people in households) that fall below the line, possibly expressed as a proportion of population. This is known as the head-count index: it pays no attention to the extent to which people fall below the poverty-line, but essentially asks whether a policy pushes more people from below to above the line than vice versa. The second statistic sums the shortfall of actual incomes below the poverty line across all people or households below the line. It is concerned with the depth of poverty, but values an extra dollar of income equally whether it goes to someone far below the line or very close to it. The final measure sums the squares of the shortfalls and thus gives an individual greater weight in the final index the further they are below the poverty line. Clearly selection of the poverty line is an important aspect of these measures. Again I do not want to enter this debate, but since I have defined the issue in terms of extreme, or abject, poverty, I am implicitly using a fairly low one. The poverty line is not necessarily the same for all countries—each country will have its own views according to custom, expectation, etc. However, once we have to aggregate across countries—for example, to consider global effects or effects on subsets of developing countries—it becomes difficult to make the case for differences. There are many reasons why people are poor, and even within broad groups there are huge differences in circumstances between individual households. Thus the effects of most shocks will differ across ‘the poor’, and a crucial part of any practical analysis must be to identify different interests within that group. A first step towards this is a poverty profile, including information on the consumption and production (including employment) activities of the poor. I do not labour the point about heterogeneity below, but in truth it is hard to over- estimate its importance. Implicitly nearly all the factors discussed will vary across the poor within a single country. While poverty profiles are a necessary input into thinking about the links between trade and poverty, they should not lead us to believe that poverty is a static and unchanging state. There is, in fact, a fairly rapid turnover of families into and out of poverty, and the determinants of those transitions appear to be rather different from those turned up by studies of the static correlates of poverty—Baulch and McCulloch (1999). This is potentially an important insight for our purposes, for if trade affects the transition probabilities it could have significant effects on the stock of ‘poor’, while apparently having little to do with that stock directly. Understanding these transitions is also a crucial component in designing policy to mitigate any adverse trade or trade policy shocks. Unfortunately, this is not an issue on which I know of any research at present; doing such work depends on first completing the more prosaic static analysis of trade and poverty that is the concern of this essay. The structure of this essay I will explore the static effects of trade and trade policy on poverty via four broad groups of institutions: enterprises, distribution channels, government and households. These are schematically arranged in Figure 1, and each is presented in a separate section below. In addition, I will discuss both longer-term dynamics— economic growth—and shorter-term dynamics— vulnerability to shocks and adjustment stresses. None of the economic analysis for the individual institutions is very complex, but in each case I shall demonstrate the possibility of both pro- and anti-poor influences. Thus when I come to put them together, it will hardly be surprising that there are no general conclusions about whether trade liberalization will increase or reduce poverty. I do, however, derive some results about the sort of circumstances under which the effects are likely to be benign and, with them, the makings of a view about how liberalization can be designed to foster poverty alleviation. Thus the essay concludes with sections on policy implications and on key questions to ask about any trade reform. One of the inevitable conclusions from a taxonomy such as this is that the impacts of trade on poverty will differ across countries. Thus great care is needed in generalizing from one country’s experience to another, and policy positions for one country will be quite unsuitable for another. B. The individual and the household A basic view of the household It is simplest to start with what economists refer to as the “farm household”—see, for example, Singh, Squire and Strauss (1986). This is not to be taken literally as referring only to people who work the land or the seas, although the rural poor account for the majority of world poverty, but to any household which makes production as well as consumption and labour-supply decisions. By 44 3 Baulch (1996) offers a useful account of different poverty measures. focusing on households I am consciously setting aside gender and intergenerational issues, but I will return to these very shortly. In this simplest case, we can think of household welfare as depending on income and the prices of all goods and services that the household faces. The former must be measured as so-called ‘full income’ comprising (a) the value of the household’s full complement of time—the maximum amount of time that could be spent working, perhaps 12 hours per person per day—valued at the prevailing wage rate, (b) transfers and other non- earned income such as remittances from family members outside the household, official transfers, goods and services in kind, and benefits from common resources, and (c) the profits from household production This view defines all the variables that need to be assessed in order to calibrate the effects of an inter- national trade policy shock on income or consumption poverty. Of course, the approach applies to all households and all shocks, but here I concentrate only on households for which poverty is an issue, (i.e. those in poverty before or after the shock, or for whom the probabilities of being in poverty are materially changed) and on shocks emanating from trade policy. The effect of a single small price change on household welfare depends on whether the household is a net supplier or net demander of the good or service in question: a price rise for something you sell makes you better off. To be more precise, to a first order of approximation, the effect of a very small price change on household welfare is proportionate to its net supply position expressed at current prices as a proportion of total expenditure. For finite price changes the household’s responses to the price change also influence the size of the welfare effect, but they will not reverse its sign. Thus, if the household has alternatives to purchasing a good whose price has risen, it can mitigate the cost of a price rise. Similarly, if it is able to switch towards an activity that has become more profitable, it can increase its gains beyond the first order amount. Responsiveness is particularly important when one considers the vulnerability aspects of poverty. Policies which reduce households’ ability to adjust to or cope with negative shocks could have major implications for the translation of trade shocks into actual poverty. Moreover, fear of the consequences of not being able to cope with negative shocks might induce households to rule out activities that would raise their average income significantly but run greater risks of very low income. Responsiveness is also important because it spreads shocks from the market in which the price change occurred to others, whose prices might not have been affected by trade policy at all. All these factors are considered below. Generalizing the household The simplest view of the household just expounded is very useful for getting our thoughts in order, but it is not very realistic. Thus we should consider a number of potential generalizations before seeking to apply it in 45 practise. Not all will be feasible or relevant in every case, of course, but among the factors to be included are: (a) Households can provide several forms of labour, so we need to consider their endowments of all these types of labour and the wages they command; (b) By talking of the ‘prevailing wage rate’, I imply that there is one wage per class of labour and that it is exogenously given to the household. In particular, this implies that household members are indifferent between working on their own farm or outside it, and that the farm is indifferent between 'home' and 'outside' workers. It is as if the farm (or family business) supplies labour to the labour market and buys it back at the given wage. But this separability might not apply—for example, because there are different costs to monitoring family and non-family workers or because family workers incur transportation costs in reaching other employers. In these cases we need to separate 'home farm' and ‘off-farm’ activities, with the prices of the former varying according to the ‘demand’ for them (i.e. their productivity) and the supply of labour to carry them out once outside activities are allowed for. (c) Once labour can undertake more than one activity, we need a way of allocating time across alternatives. If prices are exogenous the choice is easy—take the activity for which the wage is highest—whereas if ‘home’ prices are endogenous, time is allocated to equalize returns across activities (including leisure). These three generalizations allow us to think about the well-documented phenomenon that poor households typically earn income in a large variety of different ways, and that the mix of these may change significantly with trade policy changes. Indeed, the ability to switch between activities is an important aspect of adjusting to potentially impoverishing shocks—see above. (d) Some activities—and possibly some sales and purchases—may be quantity-constrained. Most obviously, some external jobs may only be available for a fixed number of hours per day—e.g. factory work or service activities such as transportation services. Particularly if trade policy flips some workers from positive to zero hours (or vice versa)—i.e. if policy moves individuals in or out of work—it could have highly significant poverty impacts. The loss of a job is probably the common proximate cause of households descending rapidly into poverty. (e) Finally, the set of factors of production owned by a household and their associated returns needs to be generalized to include land and other assets. While avoiding issues of long-run dynamics at this stage we need to recognize that such assets generate incomes and thus affect poverty. The unequal distribution of land is an important contributory factor to poverty, and while addressing it is not strictly a matter of trade policy, it clearly affects the outcomes of trade liberalization if the latter affects the rate of return to land. Genderizing the household A key extension of the approach above is to recognize the importance of intra-household distribution. It is frequently argued that the costs of poverty fall disproportionately on women, children and the elderly. Two approaches seem possible: either to work on the household and add some analytics for intra-household distribution, or to define welfare changes for individuals and add some analytics to describe inter-personal transfers. The former is probably the more straight- forward route, and the fact that the majority of data and the bulk of interventions refer to households rather than individuals suggests that policy makers and legislators see households as the fundamental unit. The easiest approach is to assume that household activities for generating welfare can be treated quite independently of those for distributing it. The analysis above describes the former, and if the determinants of the distribution of welfare across individuals are not affected by trade policy, the welfare of each person in
Tài liệu liên quan